top of page
Action for Economic Reforms

ALMONTE’S SOPHISTRY

Mr. Sta. Ana is the coordinator of Action for Economic Reforms . This article was published in the Yellow Pad column of BusinessWorld, February 14, 2005 edition, p. 21.


When former national security adviser Jose Almonte talks, we better

listen. What he says is expected to be controversial, as controversial

as his public life. Almonte was the ideologue who helped construct the

Marcos dictatorship’s program of a “new society” and a “democratic

revolution from the center.” He was the ideologue of the Ramos

administration’s liberalization program, whose unforgettable rhetoric

of NIC (Newly Industrializing Country) 2000 metamorphosed into an

economic crisis in 1997.


His history is sullied because of his involvement with the Marcos

dictatorship even as he now thinks that current problems can be

resolved democratically, albeit with a qualification. In a recent talk,

he asked the question: “Can we resolve our problems democratically?”

His response to his own question: “Yes, tentatively.”


What is perhaps consistent in him is his crusade against vested

interests. Marcos’s “revolution from the center” was an attack not only

against the Left but also against the traditional oligarchy. (Of

course, Marcos created a new oligarchy). Ramos’s liberalization program

was meant to weaken monopolists and rent-seekers. (But the Ramos

cronies were spared.) The oligarchy is Almonte’s bete noire.


For that, Almonte’s supporters call him a reformer. His opponents and

skeptics describe him as a Rasputin, a crafty manipulator. There is no

contradiction between being a reformer and being a manipulator. The end

justifies the means, as it were. The real question is whether Almonte’s

reformism strikes at the roots of the core problems.


In this regard, a recent speech of Almonte before the members of the

Foundation for Economic Freedom (its name reveals its neo-liberal

orientation) deserves scrutiny. For some, they will view Almonte’s

ideas as profound and sophisticated. For others, their conclusion will

be the opposite.


Let us go through the essential points in Almonte’s speech titled “Can

we deal with our problems democratically?” In his introduction, he

criticizes Gloria Macapagal Arroyo, for “she has failed to deploy the

moral power latent in the Presidency.” He then notes the rising

pessimism of Filipinos and “the security implications of economic and

political failure.”


Almonte asserts that the “basic problem is a failure of government.”

The Philippine state is captured by vested interests, and his

prescription is “to use the economy to reform politics.” By this, he

means to struggle against “statism” and to further “open up the economy

in the teeth of opposition from those who benefit from the status quo.”

This is a new type of nationalism — one that is “outward-looking.” In

gist, Almonte offers a solution that is consistent with a full embrace

of globalization.


Indeed, Almonte’s speech looks sophisticated. He, for instance, can sound being a globalist and a nationalist at the same time.


But there are different types of sophistication, too. Sophism is a form

of sophistication. To be straightforward, Almonte is a sophist. He is

clever in the manipulation of words and ideas, but a more trenchant

critique of his speech reveals contradictory statements, economic

misconceptions, and a distorted understanding of economic developments.


To reiterate, the main point of his speech is that the Philippines

should rely on economic integration and liberalization, for it cannot

rely on a weak state to achieve industrialization and prosperity. But

Almonte contradicts himself. At first, he acknowledges that “in the

developing world…the State must necessarily assume a vital role. And

our country’s key failing is that the Philippine State has been too

weak to carry out the interventionist policies that South Korea,

Taiwan, Singapore — even Malaysia and Thailand — all managed

successfully.” But then, he “sees our highest priority as working to

free the economy as far and as fast as we can — so that the more

impartial market can begin to make decisions our all-too fallible

politicians and bureaucrats cannot do.”


How does he escape from this contradiction? A master of sophistry, he

reasons out that government cannot be interventionist because “in our

country, dirigiste policies have merely facilitated rent-seeking and

political corruption.” Ergo, let the markets work freely.


To buttress the argument in favor of liberalization, he says that “the

spread of the market economy throughout East Asia has brought not only

higher living standards. It has also had a liberative political

effect.” A very subtle way of championing liberalization, but which is

another example of his sophistry. Almonte now equates “freeing the

economy as far and as fast as we can” with the market economy. Even in

high school economics, students already learn that the Philippines and

its fast-growing neighbors all have a market economy. The economies of

the world, except North Korea’s command economy, are in varying degrees

market economies. Some market economies have taken the bullet train

towards global economic integration; other market economies prefer

riding the slow train.


Yet, Almonte himself has pointed out that the success story in East

Asia is characterized by strong state intervention. To follow that line

of thinking, the strategy that has to be pursued then is how to

transform the weak state so it can better intervene in the (market)

economy.


Out of left field, Almonte, arrives at this conclusion: Put sweeping

political reforms at the backburner, minimize the state’s role in the

economy, and free the markets. His words: “The reformer must be willing

to settle (in the meantime) for limited political goals… In this

spirit, I suggest that, to compensate for the weaknesses of the

Philippine State, we harness the power of the market to the public

interest.”


That liberalization is a necessary condition for growth and development

cannot be proven. Evidence, on the contrary, is abundant that the

liberalization process — trade liberalization and capital account

liberalization are the main pillars — has to be approached cautiously.


Empirical papers published in refereed journals, especially those

written by Dani Rodrik, have demolished the argument that trade

liberalization predicts growth. There is no correlation between trade

liberalization and growth, no causality in the direction that trade

liberalization leads to sustained growth. In fact, what the evidence

shows is that the high-performing economies, notably China, India and

now Vietnam, have been protectionist during the initial period of

laying the basis for sustained growth. China and India are beginning to

slowly open up, only after a long period of high growth rates. Further,

the necessary reform to jump-start growth in less developed countries

involves unconventional (read: nonliberal) policies. This is the

recurring theme in papers written by Rodrik, Joseph Stiglitz, et al.


All told, what economic history shows is that countries liberalize

trade once they have become richer and more developed. (A fascinating

book is Ha-Joon Chang’s Kicking Away the Ladder — Development Strategy

in Historical Perspective, Anthem Press, which won the 2003 Myrdal

Prize, awarded by the European Association for Evolutionary Political

Economy.)


The debate on capital account liberalization has also been settled —

that it should not be rushed and that there are circumstances in which

capital control is necessary. Even the IMF has come out with a similar

conclusion in a paper (Effects of Financial Globalization on Developing

Countries: Some Empirical Evidence, 2003) that coauthored by then IMF

chief economist Kenneth Rogoff. It would take a series of financial

crises throughout the world, especially the 1997 crash in Southeast

Asia, to learn this lesson.


Let us return to Almonte’s speech: He rues the fact that “dirigiste

policies in the Philippines merely facilitated rent-seeking and

political corruption.” But it cannot be denied either that there is a

lot of rent-seeking and corruption in China and other high performing

Asian economies. Worse, from a liberal democratic viewpoint, China’s

rule of law, including the property rights regime, is more antiquated

than that of the Philippines.


{mospagebreak}


Hence, rent-seeking and corruption by themselves cannot explain growth

failure. Other variables account for the high growth in China and other

countries that are also notorious for corruption and rent-seeking in

the same way that other variables explain the low growth in the

Philippines. One insight is that while there is a high level of

corruption in both China and the Philippines, corruption in China is

more predictable and thus assuring to investors (drawn from the volume

edited by J. Edgardo Campos titled Corruption: Boom and Bust of East

Asia, Ateneo Press, 2001). The underlying message is that specific

institutional arrangements matter in the crafting of successful growth

strategies.


But can the market reform the state as suggested by Almonte? Of course,

it can. But markets can also overwhelm and hence further weaken the

state. Alas, the example used by Almonte to support his argument is

incorrect: “Considering how foreign investment is forcing even China to

adopt the rule of law by bits and pieces, I feel the open market should

become just as strong medicine for our recalcitrant polity.” In China,

the opposite is true — foreign investments follow and adjust to the

rules laid out by the Communist Party. The initial surge of private

investments occurred at the level of towns and villages, without the

benefit of formal property rights. The participation of government in

the business ventures and the profits gained from such became the

incentive mechanism for government to give security to the investors.


Along the way, the Party has made policy and institutional changes but

not because it is compelled to do so by foreign investors. Rather, the

Party is just applying the Deng Xiao Ping’s motto of “it does not

matter whether the cat is black or white so long as it catches mice,”

which is to be interpreted as choosing the most suitable instruments at

a given time to advance development objectives. The Chinese authorities

understand what Rodrik has said, i.e., “construct over the longer term

a sound institutional underpinning to endow the economy with resilience

to shocks and maintain productive dynamism.”


Almonte need not look far to see how aggressive liberalization further

undermines the state and the economy. He was a key adviser, nay, the

Rasputin of the Ramos administration that enthusiastically pursued

accelerated integration into the global economy. Yet, it was this

administration’s liberalization of the capital account that led to the

1997 financial crisis.


Almonte takes pride in the liberalization of banking entry, which is

indeed welcome but insufficient to reform the industry. The banking

system remains fragile notwithstanding liberalization. The high ratio

of nonperforming loans is an indicator. Another indicator is the

laundering that banks tolerate as in the case of the Jose Velarde and

Jose Pidal accounts. The bigger challenge then and now is how to

strengthen banking regulation and supervision.


And what about the promise of enormous benefits from trade

liberalization? Small or big businessmen from different industries want

a re-examination of the tariff policy; which has undermined Filipino

jobs and products. The tariff rates for most imported items are quite

low, well below the bounded rates of the World Trade Organization. It

goes without saying that the significant tariff cuts have also

contributed to the overall decline in revenue collection.


We can anticipate Almonte’s response to all these criticisms. In his

speech, he said: “So far, liberalization — because it has often been

timid and tentative — has been relatively easy for oligarchs to

block.” What he is suggesting is we need a bigger dose of

liberalization.


This is simplistic thinking. For one thing, public policy in a

democratic setting cannot avoid compromise. More importantly, the

big-bang approach to liberalization can be disastrous. Just compare the

experiences of Russia and China in their economic transition. Russia

rushed the market reforms, and this resulted in an economy that went

out of control, paving the way for criminals and profiteers to control

vital sectors of the economy. China, on the other hand, has been more

cautious, and despite the absence of formal property rights, the

Chinese economy has consistently registered high levels of growth.


Again, empirical studies of Rodrik show that there is no need to put in

place a comprehensive and thoroughgoing liberalization agenda, which

can only exhaust the country’s institutional capacity. The key is to

identify a very narrow set of reforms that more often than not involves

unconventional or heterodox policies.


Liberalization of course can work. In some sectors such as the airline

industry, which Lucio Tan dominates, liberalization is most welcome.

But liberalization’s overall success is predicated on the soundness of

the policy design (including the sequencing of reforms) and on the

institutional capacity (including the capacity of the state to

regulate).


The case of the liberalization of the airline industry best illustrates

this point. In spite of progressive liberalization being the official

policy, Philippine Airlines (PAL) continues to extract entitlements and

rents in the airline industry. The reason is that the Office of the

President and the regulatory body favor PAL. It is clearly a political

problem that requires a political solution.


We undeniably have to address the failure of government. But economic

liberalization cannot be the solution to this problem. The complexities

of liberalization will in fact only compound the problem.


The solution lies principally in the realm of politics. Almonte, who

mocks the Latin American countries for their old-style protectionism

and patronage, should now take a second look at the recent developments

in that region. Rejecting the neoliberal Washington Consensus that was

first experimented in their continent, the citizens of Brazil and

Argentina, the two biggest countries in South America, have installed

governments that defy the orthodoxy of liberalization. Their leaders

have introduced unconventional if not illiberal strategies that have

revitalized their economies. Brazil and Argentina are now enjoying

surprisingly high growth rates, high level of investor confidence, and

widespread mass support.


To follow the example of Brazilians and Argentines, the Filipino voters

should not elect into office parties that continue to espouse economic

dogma. In this regard, the party of Ramos and Almonte is no different

from Joseph Estrada’s party. The dominant parties in the Philippines

have allowed neoliberalism to dominate policy making.


The fact is, neoliberal economists have been in command of economic

policy making in the post-Marcos period. Also note that neoliberals

(the term was not yet coined then) like Gerardo Sicat and Cesar Virata

comprised Marcos’s economic team.


Protectionism has nowadays become a straw man. Sure, Philippine

protectionism turned out to be a disappointment. As Almonte points out,

that kind of protectionism benefited the oligarchy.


But a failure of protectionism in the past does not mean that it should

forever be rejected as a policy tool in the same way that the present

failure of liberalization should not mean that it has to be totally

discarded.


In more recent times, though, it is the neoliberals who have to be made

accountable for the failure of sustained growth and prosperity in the

Philippines.

bottom of page