top of page
Action for Economic Reforms

‘CORPORATIZATION’ OF THE BIR: GIVING REFORMS A BAD NAME

The author is the senior policy analyst and a member of the Management Collective of Action for Economic Reforms.


Last June 24, Internal Revenue commissioner Rene Banez presented his

Bureau of Internal Revenue (BIR) reform program to some members of the

NGO community. The title of his presentation – “The BIR Transformation:

Plugging the Leaks in Tax Administration” – captures the focus of his

reform agenda. It embodies a realization that defects in tax

administration account for a large part of BIR’s poor revenue

performance. His presentation also commits to introduce major

organizational changes.


The commissioner bases his realization on the observation that

substantive reforms in the past (such as the Comprehensive Tax Reform

Package or CTRP) have failed to make a difference. While many will

disagree with this premise (to be sure, a lot of substantive reforms

are also needed), the focus on tax administration reforms for the near

term makes very good sense from a policy-sequencing viewpoint. Indeed,

Philippine experience has shown that good substantive measures are

often diluted at the point of administration. Addressing administration

problems should allow the BIR to realize the theoretical advantages of

past substantive reforms, and primes it for other substantive reforms

in the future. There is also a growing awareness that tax

administration is key, and the new BIR focus should allow it to convert

such awareness – and consensus – to much-needed political support for

reforms.


Advocates of tax administration reforms will find common cause with

many of the elements of the envisioned organizational changes. The

reform program identifies eight “dimensions of organizational change,”

in particular: organizational structure; core business processes;

information and communications technology; key management systems;

human resources; leadership; group processes; and culture.


Looking at the specific measures (such as taxpayer segmentation, better

database, upgrading compensation, performance-based contracts for top

management, new filing and payment media, service orientation) within

the “dimensions” of change, we can say that they do address

long-standing problems in tax administration. They address problems in

leadership, incentive structure, payment convenience, operational

coordination and focusing of programs.


Regrettably, however, the commissioner stumbles when he labels his

reform program as the “corporatization” of the BIR. The distinctive

character of profit corporations lies in the unique way that they are

able to raise capital, limit the liability of investors, and allocate

power and control between owners and managers. The commissioner’s

reform agenda does not involve a transformation of the BIR in this

sense. Rather, they generally refer to the areas of leadership and

management system, the organizational culture, the structure of

incentives and programs. Not only do these areas vary across

corporations, the development of new approaches to these areas does not

necessarily come from corporations.


The problem becomes even more pronounced since it comes at a time when

corporate governance itself is under very critical scrutiny – even from

an efficiency standpoint. In the past, the discourse on corporate

irresponsibility focused mainly on the lack of social responsibility of

corporations. Corporations pursued their exclusively profit orientation

even if it meant doing damage to the environment, displacing

communities and maintaining unfair labor standards. At least the view

then was that corporations remained good at maximizing profit, and it

was the government’s fault that it failed to rein in the negative

externalities of corporate operations. But with the Asian crisis, and

more recently, the Enron and dot-com scandals, the discourse on

corporate responsibility (or, irresponsibility) now covers its private

sphere.


Analyses now focus on the instances of failure in the corporate system

of accountability, such as those where management intentionally hid

from its investors the true state of the corporation’s financial health

until its collapse. One might say that in the end, it is the substance

and not the label of the commissioner’s reform agenda that counts. We

disagree.


By mislabeling the reform agenda, the commissioner betrays his belief

that all government intervention is bad and profit corporations are

necessarily good. Thus, after examining the problems in tax

administration, and proposing reforms, he arrives at the generalization

that the reforms constitute “corporatization.” This is the same

“private is necessarily better” syndrome that afflicts many of our

policy makers, often with the disastrous result of either

privatization/deregulation/liberalization programs being hijacked by

vested interests, or the policy options being dogmatically narrow.

The stress on “corporatization” results in a failure to emphasize the

importance in tax administration of the commissioner’s effective

exercise of powers that are incidental to the distinctly government

power of taxation. For instance, the success of taxpayer segmentation

will require the complementary effective exercise of the commissioner’s

powers under sections 5 (power to obtain information, to summon,

examine and take testimony of persons) and 6 (power to make assessments

and prescribe additional requirements for tax administration and

enforcement) of the National Internal Revenue Code. These important

elements of tax administration reform would not have been overlooked if

the commissioner broke from the restrictive framework of

“corporatization.”


There is time to rethink the “corporatization” label of the BIR

commissioner’s reform agenda. The “corporatization” phase of the

transformation program commences in 2004 yet, and the detailed measures

have yet to be finalized. Equally important, the strategy of

corporatization should not distract from the more urgent task of

arresting the decline in revenues. The earlier the commissioner snaps

out of the corporatization syndrome, the greater the opportunity to

expand policy options and implement reforms for a better BIR.

bottom of page