top of page
  • Action for Economic Reforms

FOREIGN EXCHANGE RATE ADJUSTMENTS IN MONTHLY BILLS

The author is associate chairman of the Department of Economics of the Ateneo De Manila University.


Could foreign exchange rate adjustments in consumers’ monthly bill have

been avoided? Should government prohibit utility companies from

charging foreign exchange rate adjustments?


Practitioners of international financial economics mainly use foreign

exchange derivatives to avoid the negative consequences of foreign

exchange uncertainties. There are different types of derivatives. These

include forward, futures, options, swaps, swaptions, etc. For the sake

of simplicity and in the interest of space, this essay concentrates on

forward contracts.


In exploring, here is an example. In the early 1990s, the National

Power Corporation (Napocor) financed much of its upgrading and power

infrastructures by dollar-denominated loans.


Back then, the foreign exchange rate were approximately P25 per $1.

This implies that for every dollar that it borrowed, it had to pay back

P25. That is: if the foreign exchange rate remained the same at P25/$.

But it did not, does not, and will never. For this reason, it risked

paying less or more than P25. That is: if foreign exchange became

P10/$1, Napocor will have to pay only P10. If it became over P50/$1 and

it did, Napocor will have to pay more than P50.


This is where forward contracts come in. In this contract, a company

may deal with a financial institution to sell dollars at a

predetermined rate and at a predetermined time. For example, in 1994,

Napocor could have approached Citibank, agree to buy $1 billion at a

predetermined exchange rate of P30/$1 and a predetermined year of 2003.

This way, regardless of what happens to the exchange rate – be it

P10/$1 or P50/$1 – it assured itself of paying P30 per dollar it

borrowed.


Obviously, the example set is simpler than in reality. Amortization is

usually more complicated. Currency denomination of debts may be

diversified. Financial institutions may not commit to dealing with such

lucrative and long-term contracts with Philippine utility institutions.

And so on. But in reality, there are also more complicated derivatives

meant to deal with the complications of international finance.


Therefore, derivatives could have been used to avoid risks in foreign

exchange fluctuations.


In effect, foreign exchange rate adjustments in consumers’ monthly bill could have been avoided


The next puzzle becomes the solution to avoid this from happening

again. If the market for utility as water and electricity were

competitive to begin with, firms would have worked harder in finding

ways to cut present and future costs just to get an edge of the market.


For example, firms would have been more creative in finding ways not to

pass foreign exchange adjustment to consumers, in particular the one

that households see on their monthly bills. If government utility

companies where competent and responsible enough, they would have

insured that their foreign-denominated debt do not bloat due to peso

depreciation.


This implies that competition is the most lasting solution. With

competition, individual utility firms out-grab others for market share

by lowering price and costs. Firms may reluctantly absorb significant

amount of exchange rate costs. They would eventually hire the most

competent international financial economists to hedge.


Ultimately, they are compelled to behave responsibly for their clients’ welfare – the consumer welfare.

The catch is: converting natural monopolies to competitive firms is

easier said than done. For example, in a forum Power Issues and

Promoting Competition under the Electric Power Industry Reform Act

(sponsored by the Department of Energy, in cooperation with the

National Association of Electric Consumers for Reforms

, and hosted by the Ateneo Center for Economic Research and Development

on June 19), the consensus among participants is that the process takes

years. Therefore, raising the level of competition will not get rid of

foreign exchange risks in the short run. This calls for a short-run

solution that forces companies to hedge. The easy answer seems to

create a law that directly obliges utility companies to hedge. However,

utility companies might hedge inefficiently and not competitively

enough. The reasons follow. First, utility companies do not have much

to gain from hedging. This is because consumers bear all the risk in

foreign exchange volatility. If the exchange rate goes against

companies’ favor, they simply transfer the cost to consumers in form of

“foreign exchange adjustment.”


But if it goes in companies’ favor, there is no concrete mechanism that

forces them to refund the gains. Second, as in any insurance, hedging

carries a premium and premiums impose additional cost. In sum, utility

companies have no incentive to hedge efficiently, and in this regard,

no motivation to lower consumers’ foreign exchange costs.


As remedy, government must transfer the motivation from consumers to

firms. That is: government must force utility companies to absorb

foreign exchange cost adjustments.


This way, utility companies have everything to lose and gain from

foreign exchange fluctuations. They pay the price for gambling, and

receive the sense of certainty for hedging.

In other words, government should prohibit utility companies from charging foreign exchange rate adjustments.

Comentários


bottom of page