top of page
  • Action for Economic Reforms

NARA: HARDWOOD GONE SOFT?

The author is a professor at the University of the Philippines School of Economics. This article was originally the author’s presentation at the Annual Meeting of the Philippine Economic Society last April 10 at the Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas in Manila City.


Persistent budget deficits traceable to a falling tax effort since 1998

have focused attention on the need to reform tax administration in the

Philippines. At the moment, there are a number of proposals to reform

tax administration. These include House Bills 5054; 5465, 5546, and

Senate Bill 2463.


The template for most of these bills is from the original bill HB 5054,

also known as the “IRMA bill” (since it sought to create an “Internal

Revenue Management Authority” while abolishing the Bureau of Internal

Revenue). This has since been modified, most preeminently by HB 5465 or

the “NARA” proposal (standing for the “National Authority for Revenue

Administration”).


These proposals may be collectively called as BIR-reform bills. While

they might vary in some detail, all of them make the radical proposal

of abolishing the existing Bureau of Internal Revenue and replacing it

with a new authority vested with corporate-like powers. This authority

is to be headed by a chief executive appointed by a board composed of

both ex-officio government and full-time private representatives.


In this column, I aim to present the economic rationale for these

reforms in the light of results in the theory of incentives and

contracts. In doing so, we hope to highlight what is essential,

incidental, or contrary in the proposed measures and hopefully serve as

guide to public debate on the issue.


Weberian bureaucrats and efficiency wages


In a good deal of public discussion of the IRMA, NARA, or its various

incarnations, what has been emphasized has been the adoption of the

corporate form, and some have chosen to describe these reforms simply

as a “corporatization” of the BIR. For would-be detractors, this is a

smart tack, considering the poor record of public corporations in the

country.


Such an emphasis on the “corporatization” of the revenue-collecting agency is entirely misplaced, however.


The real innovation contained in the reform bills is not with respect

to the adoption of the corporate form, but the change in the internal

structure of incentives in that agency. Put another way, if it were

only possible to change the internal structure of incentives without

adopting a corporate form and remaining within the government

structure, then one would not have to go through the pain.


Like many other agencies in the government, however, the current BIR is

structured to approximate the ideal of a Weberian bureaucracy. The

present system presumes that tax collection work is routine, much like

sorting letters at the post office. For such tasks, “low-powered

incentives” are sufficient.


Moderate but stable pay plus secure tenure are usually sufficient to

elicit a minimum, standard effort from a Weberian bureaucrat.


While separation from such a system is still possible when performance

becomes egregiously substandard, the threshold of performance is, in

fact, not particularly high. On its own terms, such a system is

probably sufficient when output, which often consists of providing

public goods, is typically difficult to observe.


Higher-powered incentive schemes would be difficult to design in such circumstances.

Essentially, we can think of the Weberian bureaucrat as being kept in

line through an efficiency wage, which requires that the “gain” from

malfeasance should be less than the “rent” that would be lost from

separation from the service. The latter is the difference between the

actual and opportunity wage, multiplied by the probability of detection

and the long-term value of the relationship.


g < p(w – wo)N


Hence the minimum efficiency wage required to keep a bureaucrat honest is


w = (wo + g/Np)


If this efficiency wage is higher, the potential gain from malfeasance

is higher while the risk of detection and long-term prospect of the

employment are lower. The stability of employment due to permanent

tenure substitutes – to some extent – for a higher wage (N>1 is

presumably at a maximum). The nature of routine public-service tasks

makes g or the “gain” small and also makes malfeasance easy to detect,

i.e. p large.


Such a system has not worked well for the Philippines and particularly

for an agency such as the BIR for several reasons. First of all, for

many positions of responsibility – particularly such as those in the

BIR – “gain” tends to be very large. Second, the probability of

detection p is also very low, partly because of the wide latitude for

executive discretion as well as the unreliability of conviction under

the justice system.


These factors imply an efficiency wage well beyond what the government

can typically afford. If, for example, a bureaucrat’s potential gain

from corruption is as low as P1 million annually, with a probability of

detection of as high as 50% (even assuming N = 10), that bureaucrat’s

salary would have to be P200,000 more than any outside wage to keep him

from straying. This, to put it mildly, is more than anything the Salary

Standardization Law would allow.


Finally something should also be said about wo, the opportunity wage.

In some social contexts, the minimal efficiency wage for bureaucrats

need not be very high, since a malfeasant’s post-service pay would be

very low indeed. In such instances, few others would hire someone who

was dismissed for cause from the service. Here, social customs and

practices would be relevant.


In closely knit communities where reputations and one’s “good name”

might matter, an offender might be socially shunned or ostracized. This

is not currently so for Philippine society where the operative motto

seems to be pecunia non olet, and where wealth regardless of its

provenance can always buy a reputation – sometimes even seats in the

legislature.


There are obvious difficulties, therefore, why the current system of

bureaucratic rewards in the Philippines has not worked well.

A particularly tight feedback has to do with tax collections: Because

budgets are low to begin with, and therefore the current public wage is

below the efficiency wage. The result is that malfeasance increases,

causing tax collections to fall even further, making it even more

unlikely that the efficiency wage will ever be met.

{mospagebreak}


As against efficiency wages, the reform bills emphasize the central

importance of introducing incentive contracts as a paradigm to improve

the revenue effort. Under an incentive contract, the larger part of pay

is not a fixed amount but is dependent on productivity or effort,

however this is measured. Ideally, high pay or reward is associated

with high effort or the observable results of that effort. In a real

sense, even with the same job, employees “choose” their compensation by

selecting their level of effort. Probably the most familiar example of

such contracts is the piece-rate system in many factories. At the level

of executives in the private sector, the implementation of performance

bonuses and stock options is also well known.


What is somewhat novel is the intent to use such contracts in a

government agency discharging public functions. The Internal Revenue

Management Authority (IRMA) and National Authory for Revenue

Administration (NARA) bills propose that the chief executive officer

(CEO) of the new agency be governed and bound by a “performance

contract” with the revenue board. Here, the CEO will sign on to a

contract that requires him to raise collections to a certain absolute

amount. The contract might provide that any overperformance be rewarded

by an executive bonus, while underperformance might lead to a pay cut.

In the worst case, consistent underperformance could lead to

replacement, as it does in the private sector.


The basic shortcoming of a bureaucratic organization based entirely on

fixed pay is that it is too blunt to encourage performance where

variable effort and discretion are crucial for results. Unlike

bureaucratic wage contracts, incentive deals recognize the wide

latitude that revenue executives possess in determining the scope and

intensity of enforcement of tax laws.


Revenue collection is not a task bureaucrats discharge mechanically as

it entails a good amount of discretion. The approach of

bureaucratic-wage systems is progressively to delimit the scope for

such discretion by putting in place rules and complicated monitoring

mechanisms (e.g., civil service and auditing rules). By tying rewards

to performance, incentive contracts minimize external restraints and

explicitly recognize the leeway executives have. These also make

employees realize there is a choice between high and low effort.

Unlike other routine bureaucratic tasks, tax collection is one that

lends itself to some measurement. This is important since an incentive

contract can be designed only if some objective measurement of output

exists.


At the national level the “tax effort,” properly adjusted for income

growth and any new tax legislation, is literally a measure of

performance. In effect, incentive contracts abandon the mode of

monitoring that wage contracts imply.


Under a system of low-powered bureaucratic pay, no serious consequences

arise unless effort or confidence falls drastically below a certain

level; that threshold itself is defined by the standard for what is

required for dismissal from the service and lengthy court battles.


With high-powered incentives, both reward and tenure are more finely

tuned. It should be possible under such a system to replace a CEO or a

revenue district officer not necessarily because they committed an act

for which they can be charged before the Ombudsman, but simply because

they failed to fulfill a mutually agreed collection target.


To use an analogy, a bureaucratic wage contract are like ordinary

switches or circuit-breakers. Incentive contracts, meanwhile, are like

switches that include light-dimmers, or thermostats.


One thing the current bills do not do is to determine exactly who are

to be covered by incentive contracts and who are to continue to be

governed by efficiency wages. This is something that must be spelled

out in the implementing rules and regulations or by the proposed board

of the new authority.


It is obvious that such high-powered incentives would be most relevant

and applicable to the highest echelons, especially the position of CEO,

where leeway for discretion is high and there is some objective measure

of results.


However, such arrangements are likely to be impracticable for positions

involving routine jobs and those where the evaluation of a person’s

effort is more likely to be subjective. Exactly where the line must be

drawn between these two is something that still needs to be determined.


The bills now filed contemplate this issue being resolved by leaving it

up to the CEO to “establish a performance-based management system which

shall govern the selection, hiring, appointment, transfer, promotion,

or dismissal of all personnel”.


Accepting the principle of incentive or performance contracts at the

highest levels requires one to consider other incentive-design features

in the matter of hiring and firing. Incentive contracts are premised on

sufficient latitude of action for executives, and the latter would not

sign on to high-powered contracts if they did have leeway to dispose of

personnel and resources as they saw fit in order to achieve their

objectives. It is for this reason that the reform bills give a good

deal of authority to the CEO in both the appointment and removal of

personnel. Hence not only is the CEO given the authority to design the

system, but also to actually exercise the power to “appoint, fix the

remuneration and other emoluments, and remove personnel of the

authority”

{mospagebreak}


It is in the transition between the present Bureau of Internal Revenue

(BIR) and the new authority that the various versions of the reform

diverge.


The original Internal Revenue Management Authority (IRMA) states clearly that:

” No preferential or priority right shall be given to or enjoyed by any

personnel for appointment to any position in the new staffing pattern,

nor shall any personnel be considered as having prior or vested rights

with respect to retention in the Authority or in any position which may

be created in the new staffing pattern, even if such personnel should

be the incumbent of a similar position prior in organization.”


However, the National Revenue Authority (NRA) bill reverses this explicitly:

” Personnel of the (BIR) at the time of the approval of this Act who

apply for positions in the Authority shall enjoy preferential

absorption into the new organization. For the purposes of this

provision, “preferential absorption” means that (BIR) personnel who

meet the new qualification standards and selection criteria shall enjoy

priority in the hiring of personnel for the Authority. Those who cannot

be absorbed due to either the inability to meet the qualification

standards and selection criteria or the nonexistence of a suitable

position in the Authority shall be deemed separated from the service.”

. The difference – which was seen as sufficient to merit the filing of

a new bill – was explicitly an accommodation to “a reaction from

employees of the BIR who expectedly complained against the possibility

of losing their jobs.”


It has been explained that the logic of incentive contracts entails a

wide latitude being given to executives. In an ideal situation, a chief

executive officer (CEO) working under an incentive contract ought to be

allowed to bring in a team on which he or she can rely. The NRA

provision works against this logic, however, by saddling the new

authority and its CEO with the BIR’s previous personnel. There are a

number of risks such a move presents to the reform scheme.


First, such a move would have an external effect on the very hiring of

the CEO. Potential CEOs may balk at having to work with key staff not

of their own choosing. Hence the government may be faced either with a

shortage of applicants for the post. Alternatively, with the new agency

advertised as being populated by former insiders in the old agency,

there is a great possibility that the only ones willing to take on the

CEO job are themselves either unsuitable or non-serious (adverse

selection).


Related to the foregoing, a second risk are disputes and distortions

that may arise in the incentive contracts the CEOs may write with the

board. Since the CEO will not have been allowed the initial latitude to

select his or her own staff, this is a fact that can be brought out in

subsequent evaluations of performance. Then the observed nonattainment

of performance targets would be equivocal and might arguably be

attributed – not to the CEO’s failure – but to the lack of cooperation

from former insiders.


Subsequent finger pointing between the CEO and the staff not of his

choosing would then be more difficult to avoid, and the power of the

incentive contract binding the managers would be reduced. Obviously

such a risk would be averted if, to begin with, the CEO were allowed a

free hand on selecting key personnel.


These risks would not be alleviated, even by the proviso that the

absorption of old personnel should be prefaced by “qualification

standards” and “selection criteria,” or, as some have proposed, even

“lifestyle checks” on former BIR employees.


Especially in the recruitment of people for positions of trust, uniform

standards and qualifications are typically crude and inadequate; CEOs

will typically supplement these with their own subjective evaluations,

some of which are actually noncomparable and nonquantifiable. The logic

of incentive contracts is to allow executives to exercise their

discretion fully in these matters, since it is they who will ultimately

reap the consequences, for good or ill. By contrast, Sec. 20(a) of the

NRA bill harks back to the method of setting bureaucratic norms for

recruitment; it restricts the CEO’s leeway in recruitment and

effectively replaces this with a rigid rule for seniority. It is in

this sense that the NRA bill provisions on “preferential absorption”

run against the logic of the very bill itself.


There may well be good reasons that a CEO would wish to rehire a significant number of personnel from the present BIR.


Foremost among these is the fact that many of them will have a great

deal of experience. But the importance of experience as against other

qualities of staff should, properly speaking, be regarded as a call by

management, not an imposition by the law.


I have approached this issue primarily from the viewpoint of

safeguarding the integrity and efficiency of future contracts under the

proposed new revenue authority.


The proponents of the NRA bill in its relevant provisions, on the other

hand, seem concerned with extending the integrity of contracts under

the existing BIR. This appears to be unnecessary.


In the first place, legal provisions and civil service rules clearly

apply regarding the fate of positions in agencies that have been

abolished. Secondly, the law also provides for the compensation of

those who have been terminated through separation or retirement

benefits, about which more below.


If any rule on “preferential absorption” is instituted at all, it

should apply only to positions that will not be covered by incentive

contracts in the authority to be established. This would exclude most

positions in top to middle management.


The reasoning from the incentives viewpoint is clear: those to be

compensated with efficiency wages are presumably those who exercise

little or no discretion in the overall affairs of the authority. They

can be granted the usual wage- and tenure-security packages under

existing labor laws. Standard qualifying procedures may be properly

applied to recruiting these, since they are destined to perform routine

tasks whose outcomes are easily monitored.


By contrast, positions of trust and confidence should be covered by

incentive contracts, with the implied absence of any claim to tenure.

Indeed a good number of such positions should be coterminous with that

of the CEO.


A word must be said finally about an apparently innocent issue, which

is the amount of severance pay to be paid. The IRMA bill (Section 21)

states that:


” The officials and employees of the former Bureau of Internal Revenue

who are separated from the service as a result of the organization of

the Authority shall be allowed to retire or be separated from the

service under existing laws.”


Existing civil service rules allow for one-month’s pay for every year

of service rendered. As a concession to the protests of the BIR

employees. The NRA bill, on the other hand, promises separation

incentives:


” which shall be in addition to all gratuities and benefits to which they may be entitled under existing laws”.


The NRA bill states that it intended to correct the “mistaken notion”

that there would be no retirement or separation benefits. It went

further however, by holding out the possibility of separation benefits

over and above what existing laws allow. The greater generosity of the

NRA version was also motivated by the need to appease the current

employees. Some in Congress are now said to offer three- to five-months

pay per year of service to those to be separated. Needless to say, such

amounts would be budget-busters at just a time the country least needs

these.


Proponents of the NRA bill were obviously motivated by some form of the

Pareto Compensation Principle: if the gains from the policy measure are

so great, they could compensate the potential losers from it.


One problem with this application, however, is the precise

identification of “losers” in this context. While one can readily go

along with the proposition that “not everyone in government is

corrupt,” this is far from saying that “no one in government is corrupt

– particularly in the BIR.”


Extraordinary compensation may go some way towards justly assuaging

those genuinely harmed by retrenchment. But the law is carrying a leaky

bucket when it promises generosity to all, even to those who profited

from their positions and amassed wealth. Viewed this way, one is no

longer certain where Pareto Compensation ends and where coercion

begins.

Comentarios


bottom of page