top of page
Action for Economic Reforms

TERRIFIED BY TARIFFICATION?

The author is the team leader of the advocacy component of the ADB-DA Grains Sector Development Program and was DA undersecretary for policy and planning, 1988-1992.


Two bills currently under consideration in the legislature are of great

importance: House Bill (HB) 3339, filed by Speaker Jose de Venecia and

Rep. Ben Cruz, and Senate Bill (SB) 1912 filed by Sen. Manuel Villar.

Both bills are entitled: AN ACT TO PLACE SAFETY NETS FOR FILIPINO RICE

PRODUCERS BY IMPOSING TARIFFS IN LIEU OF QUANTITATIVE RESTRICTIONS ON

RICE IMPORTS, DIRECTING TARIFF COLLECTIONS FROM RICE IMPORTS TO

PROJECTS AND PROGRAMS THAT ENHANCE RICE PRODUCTIVITY AND INCREASE

FARMERS’ INCOMES, AND FOR OTHER PURPOSES – or in short, the “RICE

SAFETY NET ACT OF 2001.”


Rice Trade Policy and Performance: The NFA Monopoly


Under current policy – as codified in Presidential Decree 4 of 1972,

the government sets – through an administrative process – the amount of

rice that may be exported out of, or imported into, the country. This

policy of quantitative restrictions, or QRs, is implemented by the

National Food Authority (NFA), which is accorded the sole authority or

the monopoly on all international trade of rice. As a government

entity, the NFA’s decisions on international rice trade are heavily

influenced by politics and hampered by bureaucratic constraints and

inefficiency.


The policy to maintain government monopoly on rice trade was intended

to protect BOTH rice farmers and consumers. Farmers were to be assured

of palay (paddy or unmilled rice) prices above market levels. Consumers

would be served by NFA ensuring that retail rice prices are below

market levels. Furthermore, the NFA was expected to stabilize these

prices. Thus, the strategy of the NFA is often described as: “buy high,

sell low and hold long.”


The NFA’s operations are financed by the National Government. Over the

last decade, the NFA has received budgetary appropriations and equity

of at least P1 billion per year. The NFA has also been allowed by the

Department of Finance to borrow, with the government’s guarantee, up to

P20 billion from commercial banks, both local and foreign.


The evidence of the past 28 years since 1972 is clear: the monopoly policy has failed.

Over the 1990s, the NFA only procures an average of less than 3% of all

palay produced. With such a small procurement capacity, the NFA is able

to serve only about 70,000 out of over two million rice farmers.


On the other hand, the great mass of 80 million Filipino consumers

suffer rice prices that are double to triple those borne by Thai or

Vietnamese households. Recent surveys show that only about 15% of

Filipino households – including farmers, are able to purchase NFA rice

sold at below-market prices.


As of August 2001, the wholesale price of regular-milled rice in the major Manila wet markets was P16.53 per kilo.


The cheapest rice in the Philippines is regular milled sold at P14 per kilo by the NFA in its relatively few “rolling stores.”


In the most depressed areas, the stocks of the NFA’s rolling stores are

not fully exhausted, indicating that even P14 is apparently expensive

to the very poor!


The gap in consumer price and producer cost between the Philippines on

the high side, and Thailand and Vietnam on the low side has been

growing since the mid-1980s.


For the same quality of rice that Filipinos consume, Vietnamese

households pay only P6.36 per kilo, while Thai households pay P7.54 per

kilo – less than half the prices faced by Filipino households!

Also, Thai, Vietnamese and world rice prices have been more stable than Philippine rice prices.


Furthermore, when NFA imports rice, the 50% tariff currently required

by the Tariff and Customs Code is waived. This has resulted in forgone

tariff revenues to the government averaging about P4 billion per year

between 1995 and 2000.


Proposed Legislation to ‘Tariffy’ Rice QRs


HB 3339 and SB 1912 remove government monopoly on rice international

trade by “tariffying” the QRs on rice. The bills propose the

replacement of the QR on rice with an import tax or tariff that

provides protection equivalent to that currently given to rice farmers

under QRs. Therefore rice farmers and the rice industry will continue

to be protected – but by tariffs, not by QRs.


Under the “tariffied” system, the NFA may continue to exist, operate

and trade as a government corporation, but no longer as a monopoly. All

entities – including farmers, cooperatives, agribusiness enterprises,

traders, associations and consumers may engage in international rice

trade, responding to trading opportunities that emerge from the cycles

of production and prices not only in the country but also

internationally.


All rice importers and exporters will pay the required tariffs and

taxes to the Bureau of Customs. The import tariffs that represent the

“tariff-equivalent” level of protection are estimated at between 70%

and 100%.


HB 3339 and SB 1912 propose that the tariff revenues will be directed

to the Rice Farmers Development Fund that is dedicated to the financing

of crucial support services for rice farmers.


Filipino rice farmers badly need crucial public goods and support

services so that they can make a decent living from rice farming and be

competitive with other rice producing countries such as Vietnam and

Thailand.


The crucial support services required include: communal and private

irrigation, high-yielding seeds, efficient transport networks and

effective extension systems. However, the Philippine budget can hardly

provide for the cost of the crucial support services.


However, the design of the Rice Farmers Development Fund must ensure

that the mistakes made with the Agricultural Competitiveness

Enhancement Fund (ACEF) created under RA 8178 (Agricultural

Tariffication Act of 1995), will be avoided.


International Trade in Rice and WTO and ASEAN


The Philippines is one of only three countries worldwide which were

granted exemptions in 1995 from the removal of QRs on rice, under Annex

5 of the WTO agreement. The others were Japan and South Korea.

In April 1999 Japan gave up its QR for a high tariff rate on rice.

South Korea has already announced it is ready to give up rice QRs and

is designing alternative protection modes. The Philippines will soon be

the only country still claiming exemption from the tariffication of

rice QRs.


The exemption from the tariffication of rice QRs under the WTO expires on December 31, 2004.


Currently the Philippines is the only country in the ASEAN that still relies on QRs to protect its rice sector.


The Philippines has pledged that rice will be covered by the ASEAN CEPT by January 1, 2005.


Rice Smuggling


Since rice prices in the Philippines are so much higher than rice

prices from exporting countries like Vietnam and Thailand, it is

particularly profitable to smuggle rice into the country, despite the

risks of being caught and penalized.


World rice prices have fallen steadily over the past decade. In

contrast, Philippine rice prices have climbed fairly rapidly. These

trends have provided greater incentives and rewards for importers and

smugglers.


The enforcement of anti-rice smuggling rules and regulations is very

weak, given the archipelagic nature of the country and the poor

resources provided to enforcement authorities.


When rice is found to be smuggled, it is confiscated and later sold by

the government in the domestic market. Thus even smuggled rice still

adds to total domestic rice supply.


HB 3339 and SB 1912 propose that part of the tariff revenues from rice

imports be directed to the financing of intensified anti-smuggling

efforts.


Not Terrified by Tariffication


In summary, the proposed change in rice policy is the correct direction

for the government. HB 3339 and SB 1912 lessen bureaucratic constraints

and political influence on rice trade, while maintaining protection and

also enabling the generation of much needed tariff revenues. The

revenues are directed toward the enhancement of productivity, which

will lay the foundation not only for sustainable farmer

competitiveness, but also stable national food security.

bottom of page